Below is an article in Washington Post. The author believes that some subsidies such as educational and health are beneficial, but the quran disallow any subsidy so we should stay away from any subsidy. Instead, the government just give cash handouts which is demanded by the quran.
https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/monkey-cage/wp/2015/07/16/state-subsidies-take-from-the-poor-to-give-to-the-rich/
State subsidies take from the poor to give to the rich
Analysis by M. Steven Fish
and July 16, 2015 at 8:09 a.m. EDT
What’s
the worst thing a government can spend its people’s money on?
Progressives might say the military; conservatives might point to
entitlement programs. But outlays in both of these areas do at least
pump money into the economy and create jobs, and most people would agree
that some spending on each is justifiable.
In
one area, however, government spending almost always redistributes
income from the poor to the rich, encourages inefficiency and fuels
corruption: state subsides.
By
state subsidies, we mean government assistance to boost producers’
incomes above or reduce consumers’ expenditures below what they would be
in a competitive marketplace. State subsidies might seem an unlikely
candidate for this charge. After all, they are often viewed as tools of
mercy. According to their advocates, governments use them to make goods
and services more affordable to the poor, assist aspiring entrepreneurs
or to save jobs in enterprises that can’t endure the pressures of the
market without assistance.
But
scratch the surface of most state subsidies and you will find much more
flowing into the bank accounts of the well-heeled than into the pockets
of the poor.
New research shows that state subsidies are the opposite of Robin Hood
A wave of recent political science publications, including our research on post-communist Europe (see also here and here),
underscores this point. Far from aiding the downtrodden, state
subsidies have enriched and empowered corrupt capitalists who have
undermined the establishment of honest state administrations and
judicial systems.
In
Ukraine, oligarchs who built their fortunes on state budgetary
transfers, crony-engineered loans, and selective tax breaks continue to
dominate the business world today. State subsidies like these ended up
bankrupting the country and help explain its ineffective response to a light-handed military intervention by Russia.
The most egregious state subsidies of all take place in the gas market. Fixed gas prices do benefit Ukrainian households — but in the most inefficient way imaginable.
The real beneficiaries are shadowy intermediaries that have made
billions of dollars buying gas at cheap state prices and reselling it at
huge markups to industrial consumers and the state gas company.
In
2012 alone, the state’s energy subsidies amounted to 7 percent of
Ukraine’s entire gross domestic product — the same amount that Ukraine
spent on defense and health care combined. An estimated 40 percent of the energy subsidies were stolen
by individuals linked to then-President Viktor Yanukovych. Eliminating
the state subsidy for the oligarchs would generate more than enough
savings to assist gas purchases by the poor.
The post-communist region is replete with governments that have chosen to prop up insolvent state companies
with subsidies rather than shut them down, thereby allowing their
managers to get rich by systematically ripping off the companies’
assets.
There is perhaps a single exception to this pattern in the region, and that is Estonia. Shortly after independence in 1991, the Estonian government virtually eliminated subsidies.
It rapidly and consistently imposed hard budget constraints on firms.
It reined in state assistance to unprofitable companies, shuttered
insolvent state banks, and introduced effective bankruptcy and currency
regimes. The beneficiaries of the state subsidies cried foul, but the
government stayed the course. The result was a level economic playing
field in which real entrepreneurs rather than corrupt political
capitalists could thrive. The policies marginalized predatory business
interests opposed to the rule of law and enabled Estonian leaders to
build a state administration that stands out in the post-communist
region for its probity and efficiency.
The
perverse effects of state subsidies are hardly limited to
post-communist countries. In Nigeria, a fuel subsidy program touted as a
way of helping the poor primarily benefits corrupt state officials and their cronies.
The state mandates a fixed retail price for petrol of pennies on the
dollar and then compensates wholesalers for the difference between the
low retail price and the market price they pay to import the fuel. In
reality, the government-connected wholesalers overstate their imports by
billions of dollars, thereby stealing off with the equivalent amount in
subsidies.
In
India, grain producers are required to sell to government middlemen at
above-market prices. The policy’s original intent was to aid poor
farmers, but its main beneficiaries are the middlemen themselves and
well-to-do agricultural interests from rich provinces such as Punjab and
Haryana. The policy inflates grain prices, thereby abusing the poor
majority that spends most of its income on food. Funds for the state
subsidies could be spent instead on roads that would help farmers get
their goods to market. But investment in infrastructure lags. As a
result, one-third of all fruits and vegetables in India rot before they
reach consumers.
U.S. cotton subsidies
have much in common with India’s grain subsidies, except that they
generate disastrous global effects on top of their domestic
consequences. U.S. taxpayers shell out $3 billion to $4 billion per year
to finance the government’s program to keep a few thousand big cotton
farmers rich. The policies depress world cotton prices and reduce the
incomes of millions of small cotton farmers in some of the world’s poorest countries, including Niger, Burkina Faso, Mali, Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan.
So why are state subsidies popular?
State
subsidies tend to be popular for three reasons. First, they usually
include a bone for the poor. In Ukraine, the fuel subsidies reduce
prices for consumers. In India, the grain-buying program raises the
selling price that smaller farmers fetch. So while state subsidies are
terribly inefficient and unfair, the little guy tends to feel he’s
getting something, even if it’s a pittance.
Second,
the government officials and well-endowed private interests who are the
biggest beneficiaries have political clout. They use their influence
over the government and media to trumpet the supposed benefits of state
subsides for the masses.
Third,
opinion leaders in academia and the media provide intellectual cover
for state subsidies. Well-meaning but poorly informed, some social
scientists and public commentators in both the West and developing
countries assume that anything that the IMF endorses, including reducing
state subsidies, amounts to an attack on the underprivileged (see here, here, here, and here).
Add
to this the problem that those who benefit from state subsidies are
normally more motivated to keep them than their victims are to scrap
them and you have the makings of a grand injustice that is very hard to
eradicate. State subsidies’ main beneficiaries are concentrated,
well-organized, and well-informed, while the losers are diffuse,
numerous, and often unaware of their losses. How often do we see big public demonstrations against state subsidies?
Some subsidies do good.
Well-designed,
need-based subsidies for poverty-alleviation can indeed be beneficial.
Likewise, states justifiably subsidize education, health care and
infrastructure since these are public goods that market forces alone
cannot generate in sufficient amounts. But market forces are
adequate to ensure the production and distribution of fuel and wheat. If
some consumers are too poor to afford the goods, the state could
provide targeted transfers to help them pay.
But
state subsidies that go beyond providing poverty relief and public
goods have a reverse Robin Hood effect. Fuel subsidies, in particular,
also tend to generate shortages, kindle corruption and encourage
patterns of consumption that degrade the environment.
Steven Fish is a professor of political science at the University of California at Berkeley. Neil
A. Abrams received his doctorate in political science from the
University of California at Berkeley. He is completing a book on
corruption in Ukraine.
No comments:
Post a Comment